March 6, 2017
Do You Want to Restore Manufacturing
Employment? Smash the Robots!
There has been much public discussion about the demise of
U.S. manufacturing jobs and policies to restore manufacturing employment.
Indeed, as shown in Chart 1, in absolute as well as relative terms, U.S. manufacturing
employment has declined in the post-WWII era. In absolute terms, U.S.
manufacturing employment started falling precipitously in the 2000s and has
been especially hard hit since the Great Recession. (Shaded areas in this and subsequent charts
represent periods of economic recession.) U.S. manufacturing employment
relative to total U.S. nonfarm employment has been trending lower throughout
almost the entire post-WWII era. While relative manufacturing employment has
been trending lower for almost 70 years, manufacturing’s relative contribution to total real GDP (see Chart 2), after
ebbing during the 1980s and early 1990s, staged a resurgence in late 1990s
until the Great Recession. Although foreign trade is being advanced by some as
the reason for the secular decline in U.S. manufacturing, I will argue that
technology is the principal factor accounting for this phenomenon.
Chart 1
Chart 2
Let’s examine the relationship between U.S. net exports
of goods and manufacturing output
relative to total output. Plotted in Chart 3 are annual averages of U.S. real net exports of durable goods (real
exports of goods minus real imports of goods) as a percent of total real GDP
and annual averages of real GDP value-added of manufacturing as a percent of
total real GDP. U.S. manufacturing output relative to total real GDP reaches a
post-WWII low in 1981 and climbs back to its highest level since 1972 in 2006.
Notice that as U.S. manufacturing relative GDP was oscillating higher from the early 1980s through the
mid 2000s, the U.S. real net exports in durable goods relative to real GDP was oscillating lower. For historical reference,
NAFTA was signed in 1994, the U.S. joined the WTO in 1995 when it came into
existence and Mainland China joined the WTO in December 2001. So, U.S. manufacturing started making
greater contributions to total GDP after NAFTA
and after Mainland China joined the
WTO. That is, U.S. manufacturing started making greater contributions to total GDP as the U.S. trade deficit in durable
goods was enlarging up until the
Great Recession.
Chart 3
So if foreign trade deficits are not a satisfactory
explanation of the secular decline in U.S. manufacturing employment, what is? A
secular increase in manufacturing-worker productivity. The data in Chart 4 compare
the real GDP value-added of manufacturing per manufacturing employee, a crude
measure of manufacturing-worker productivity, with the total number of
manufacturing employees. Both series are converted to index numbers with their
respective 1950 values set equal 100. If manufacturing workers are becoming
more productive over time, that is, as time progresses, one manufacturing
employee is able to produce a greater real value of manufacturing output than
in previous years, the index number of the real GDP value-added of
manufacturing per manufacturing employee would be higher. In fact, in 2015,
this index number stood at 776. This means that a manufacturing worker in 2015
could produce 676% more output than she could in 1950 (776 represents a 676%
increase vs. 100). This translates into a compound annual rate of growth in
this crude measure of manufacturing-worker productivity of 3.25% from 1950
through 2015. The index number of total manufacturing employment in 2015 stood
at 88, meaning that there were 12% fewer manufacturing employees then compared
to 1950 (88 represents a 12% decline vs. 100). Given the secular increase in
manufacturing-worker productivity, it is not surprising that there has been a
secular decline in the number of people employed in manufacturing.
Chart 4
The data in Chart 5 help explain the secular increase in
manufacturing-worker productivity. Along with the index of real GDP value-added
of manufacturing per manufacturing employee, again a crude measure of
manufacturing-worker productivity, I have added the index of the real net stock
of business equipment per manufacturing employee – a crude measure of the
capital-to-labor ratio in manufacturing. Give a woman a brace-and-a bit set,
and she can drill more holes in a given amount of time. Give a woman an
electric drill, and she can drill even more holes in the same amount of time.
Give a woman a drilling robot to run, and she can drill yet even more holes in
the same amount of time. In other words, the more equipment and more technologically-advanced
equipment a manufacturing worker has to work with, the more output can be
produced by that worker in a given amount of time. As the capital-to-labor
ratio in manufacturing rises, so should worker productivity rise. And that is
what the data plotted in Chart 5 indicate.
Chart 5
The moral of this story is that if America wants to
restore manufacturing employment to its former glory, the federal government
should form a search-and-destroy task force with the authority to enter
manufacturing facilities in the U.S. to smash robots, computers and any other
labor-saving equipment the deputized task force deems appropriate. Then there
will be a tremendous increase in demand for U.S. manufacturing employees. Of course, manufacturing output will grow
more slowly and the prices of manufactured goods will skyrocket. But, hey,
the goal of increased manufacturing employment will have been achieved.
Paul L. Kasriel
Founder, Econtrarian LLC
Senior Economic and Investment Advisor
1-920-818-0236
“For most of human history, it made good adaptive sense to
be fearful and emphasize the negative; any mistake could be fatal”, Joost
Swarte